Independent Treasury (United States)
From the 1840s until 1863 the Independent Treasury, as it was
called, divorced the government’s fiscal operations from private sector banks.
It accepted payment for public obligations—taxes—only in gold and silver specie
and treasury notes, and operated its own depositories around the country. The
Independent Treasury did not accept bank notes, and did not hold deposits in
commercial banks. Its own depositories were separate from state banks.
The Independent Treasury was born of the freewheeling banking environment
that flourished after the demise of the Second Bank of the United States. At
first, the Treasury tried to supply a modicum of regulatory discipline by
holding Treasury deposits in state banks and requiring special specie reserves
for those deposits. The Treasury found, however, that its own deposits could be
held hostage to overly aggressive lending policies of state banks, and on
occasion the Treasury could not withdraw its funds. During this time gold and
silver specie commanded a reverence in the eyes of a public that distrusted
banks, bank notes, and even corporations themselves. Large segments of the
public saw bank notes as a sham scheme of the “moneyed interests” to exploit the
unwary, and the proponents of the Independent Treasury were “hard currency”
people who wanted the government’s business separated from banks and
corporations.
The Sub-Treasury Act of 1840 became law during the presidency of Martin Van
Buren, a staunch advocate of the hard currency policies that marked the presidency of
his predecessor, Andrew Jackson. Daniel Webster stood flatly opposed to the
bill, remarking on 12 March 1938 that “[t]he use of money is in the exchange. It
is designed to circulate, not to be hoarded. To keep it that is to detain it is
a conception belonging to barbarous times and barbarous governments” (Chown,
1994). Opponents of the bill saw it turning the Treasury into a hoarder of gold
and silver, and throwing the private sector into a deflationary spiral. Banks
held gold and silver specie to act as reserves for the redemption of bank notes.
If the government began absorbing gold and silver specie, banks would be forced
to contract the supply of circulating bank notes.
After heated political combat, Congress enacted the Sub-Treasury Act on 30
June 1840. It provided that in the first year one-fourth of public obligations,
that is, taxes, should be paid in specie, and by 1843 100 percent of public
obligations should be paid in specie. In 1843 Congress repealed the first
Sub-Treasury Act.
In 1846 Congress enacted a second Sub-Treasury bill. This bill required that
government offices accept only gold and silver specie and treasury notes
(nonlegal-tender paper money issued by the Treasury) in payment of public
obligations. The Independent Treasury System lasted in some form until 1920. As
early as 1863, however, the Treasury began to hold deposits in commercial
banks.
In its pre–Civil War phase, the Independent Treasury proved that the fears of
some of its critics were well founded. Problems arose because Treasury tax
collections did not coincide with government expenditures. When tax collections
rose above government payments, specie left private banks, and entered Treasury
depositories, forcing banks to contract bank note circulation. When government
payments overtook tax collections, specie flowed into the banking system, and
banks issued more bank notes. The ebb and flow of specie from Treasury
depositories imparted a cyclical motion to the supply of circulating bank notes,
and acted to destabilize the economy. After the Treasury was allowed to maintain
commercial bank deposits, the Treasury learned to conduct the government’s
fiscal operations without rocking the banking system.
The Independent Treasury System represents another episode in the paper money
drama that would eventually define the terms on which the public would come to
accept paper money. It represented a phase in which societies had come to accept
precious metal coins, something that could not be taken for granted in ancient
societies. Despite the acceptance of precious metal coins, feelings about paper
money ran high, and suspicion about paper money gained ground quickly in hard
times. Distrust of paper money left a social seam, often hidden, but always
threatening to rip open and become a power force in political life.
No comments:
Post a Comment